The data used in all analyzes is presented in two spreadsheets
available for download. The sources of this data is one
government report or another: IRS, Census Bureau, Bureau of Labor
Statistics, even the CBO.
Time line trends of income are generally computer using a form of
the CPI, consumer price index. There are some serious limitations
in this analyses. Also the general lack of inclusion of taxes
paid and welfare received do not reflect well on the actual differences
between quintiles of income.
CPI and the Gini Coefficient are defined and analyzed for use in our
investigation into income distribution, in order to be sure that the
conclusions drawn are valid. CPI has some limitations in the
manner in which many use it to analyze time trends in income.
It is clear that the standard approach is not sufficient, and
therefore in the next Chapter we will be exploring modifications to the
popular idea that the "rich are getting richer at the expense of the
poor."
We do see two distinct periods: a flat period
up to the 60's and
then a growth in income distribution since.
The Data and its sources, where is it from?
Saez on Income Share of Top 10%
The sources of the base data on income is from the IRS,
Census
Bureau, some from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, and even Forbes
(for the richest 400). The spreadsheets from Saez, et all have been used in many articles which
generally promote the inequality is a growing theme.
The data from each source has been collected into some
spreadsheets which are available from this webpage
Here.
Each data source has its limitations. In the case of the
IRS data, reported income is critically dependent on the Tax code at
that time. Saez puts forth the oft referenced curve shown at right as
indicative of a growing inequality in income distribution.
It has been used extensively as proof of a growing inequality in
income, but rarely are questions asked as to its validity and the
causes of this growth. Also this data shown in the graph
at right does not include transfer payments.
The top 10% of income makers experienced over a time period
from the early '40s to the early '80s of relatively flat income
distribution. From that time of the late '70s, the
income share (percentage of the total national reported income)
crept up for a variety of reasons, which we will delve into in
coming chapters. We do however have 2 distinctly different
periods having different forces operating.
First of all we should point out that this is the top 10% of tax units,
essentially tax filers. This relates to the population and
households in the graph shown nearby. The ratio of
households to the total population (is nearly the same as Tax units)
is not a fixed number over this time period, nor is the
number of people in a household the same for all income levels.
The number of households from 1967 to 2010 rose over 3X.
What we do see is
that at the high end of income earners, the percentage of income
reported was larger in percent of total. The Gini coefficient
rose gradually during this entire time period, from 1967. This
time period is the focus of our study here.
The history of the tax code is also pertinent here, as the taxes
on some forms of income changed dramatically in the '80s to wit it
was more advantageous to declare income than to have other forms not
tied to tax unit declaration.
So the data waters are getting a little murky as we proceed deeper
into the details. So in closer examination of the data
we can, in the next section consider the notion of how well did the
populace do in bettering their lives. For if the rich did
became richer, at the same time a good deal of the public were also
much better off then we can raise another question.
There are some pieces of this puzzle to consider before we can
answer that question.
Historical Trends: how computed
The historic trends are often in the form of either percent share or
inflation adjusted dollars. The percent share is simply the
ratio of different groups to each other or to the total. The
adjustment for inflation is usually stated in something like 2010
dollars. The manner in which the data is corrected for
inflation is to use a form of CPI to correct previous years to the
current year. Since one parameter CPI is used for all consumption,
there is an inherent limitation (see below).
The trend data is rarely shown with taxes and transfer payments
included. None of the data above shows the effect on
income after taxes and welfare. The effects of both will be
considered below in the discussion on Gini coefficient and in the
next Chapter.
There has been a preference to show median data rather than mean
data for the express reason that one large value can raise the mean.
However since the number of households in each category is large,
using the mean can provide a better idea of the total average income
in each quintile. The data for each type will be compared in
the next Chapter for completeness.
Clearly the ratio of different quintiles using the mean value is
not often done, but offers a means to better understand the
progression of income increase over time. This will be one of
the data set comparisons presented in the next Chapter.
CPI and all of its limitations
The Consumer Price Index has seem changes over time in how it is
computer, and what its definition is. See this
Link for the
definition of the various CPI's used for different reasons. The
history of the various definitions and how the data is collected is also
a factor in the quality of the values of CPI, and how it can be used.
For one distinction, CPI is gathered for the urban population only.
The
inherent limitation in its use for long-term trends is that tries to
collage all variability over the quintiles into a single parameter.
CPI is useful in showing the inflation trends in recent years. But
to describe how the lower quintile makes consumption decisions over time
is not well represented with the CPI approach.
One attempt to correct for
differences in consumption between the lowest quintile and the others
is shown at right and is based upon the adjustment of 0.8 percentage
points lower inflation for the poor. This correction for CPI
is well argued by Sullivan and
Meyer and by
Cato. This graph also shows how close all of the standard
CPI curves are over time: University Calculator,
Worksheet numbers, Saez data. One can also make a heuristic
argument that the inflation rate for the rich would be higher over
this time period. The inflation adjustment of 0.8 percent
higher is also presented in this graph. These curves will be
used to generate a What-If analysis on the income distribution in a
later Chapter.
The data analysis shows that the simple CPI will grossly
overestimate both the number that are poor historically and
presently, and that the consumption equality is more apparent when
seeing the actual consumption habits over time.
The cost of food for instance has fallen from 17% of GDP in the
60's to under 5% of GDP today, on average. While no doubt the
difference between the expenditures of the rich and poor in this
category have diverged substantially. Take any consumable
today and divide the current price by 6 (see graph above) and ask
the question is that result less than what I paid back in the 60's?
In some cases the answer is yes and in other cases the answer is no.
How your well-being improved is therefore the question.
Clearly in housing and energy the corrected cost is still higher
than what was available then. In many cases we are better off
today, such as in food. All of the segments of the economy
that have seen the most truly free market are more than likely
cheaper now in real dollars than back then.
The Gini coefficient is simply put the ratio of areas under a
specific curve. See this
link for an in depth definition.
Suffice it to say that the larger the Gini value, the more the income
distribution is farther from a 45 degree line, which represents
completely equal income for all of the population. In such a case
the Gini value would be 0. For the case where all of the income is
made by a very small portion of the population, the Gini coefficient is
close to 1.
In 1993, the Census Bureau began using a new method of collecting
income data, allowing respondents to report greater income values in the
Current Population Survey. A change that may affect only a small number
of cases (particularly those at the upper end of the income
distribution) can have a considerable effect on inequality measures,
like the Gini coefficient and shares of aggregate income, while making
little or no change to median income. This however had a profound effect
on the upper end of the income distribution by recording income levels
that had been previously underreported. The impact of this change on
measured income inequality was quite large, and we are unable to
determine precisely the proportion of the increase in income inequality
between 1992 and 1993 that is attributable to this change.
The sensitivity to large swings in income distribution over time
is however possible. To say that there is an ideal Gini value
or that it should remain constant is not an acceptable or plausible
approach.
The effects of race and geography are analyzed, with Backs and
Hispanics realizing a larger distribution of income and therefore a
higher Gini coefficient perhaps by as much as 0.05. Most
of the USA is near the average of Gini = 0.46. Countries
across the world report their income distribution in presumably
disparate ways, but nevertheless the values vary from the low 0.3
range to nearly 0.6 (for China and India).
In the case of having a large value for some period of time,
that might indicate a growth spurt in the economy. Even
Inequality Advocates have argued that the income distribution is
unequal during some significant changes in the economy. The
transition from a manufacturing economy to a information and skill
based economy is such a transition. A topic to explore in the
next Chapter.
Data is data and conclusions are conclusions, and
hopefully there is some solid relationship between them.