First the USA is the most progressive in its taxing than other
countries like France.
Once higher tax rates cause the top 1% to report less income, then
top taxpayers would likely pay a much smaller share of taxes, just as
they do in, say, France or Sweden.
In The Journal of Economic Perspectives (Winter 2007), Messrs.
Piketty and Saez estimated that "the upper 1% of the income distribution
earned 19.6% of total income before tax [in 2004], and paid 41% of the
individual federal income tax." No other major country is so dependent
on so few taxpayers.
The advocates of more redistribution see the rich as having the
party. Life should be seen more as a means to happiness not having
a party.
As the
headline of a Robert Creamer column in the Huffington Post put it: "The
Crowd that Had the Party Should Pick up the Tab."
The effect of taxes and transfer payments is large.
Links:
Forces Catalog: driving forces
on income distribution.
"Taxes and the Top Percentile Myth" by Reynolds:
Link
A 2008 OECD study of leading economies found that 'taxation is most
progressively distributed in the United States.' More so than Sweden or
France.
When President Obama announced a two-year stay of execution for
taxpayers on Dec. 7, he made it clear that he intends to spend those two
years campaigning for higher marginal tax rates on dividends, capital
gains and salaries for couples earning more than $250,000. "I don't see
how the Republicans win that argument," said the president.
Despite the deficit commission's call for tax reform with fewer tax
credits and lower marginal tax rates, the left wing of the Democratic
Party remains passionate about making the U.S. tax system more and more
progressive. They claim this is all about payback—that raising the
highest tax rates is the fair thing to do because top income groups
supposedly received huge windfalls from the Bush tax cuts.
As the
headline of a Robert Creamer column in the Huffington Post put it: "The
Crowd that Had the Party Should Pick up the Tab."
Arguments for these retaliatory tax penalties invariably begin with
estimates by economists Thomas Piketty of the Paris School of Economics
and Emmanuel Saez of U.C. Berkeley that the wealthiest 1% of U.S.
households now take home more than 20% of all household income.
This estimate suffers two obvious and fatal flaws. The first is that
the "more than 20%" figure does not refer to "take home" income at all.
It refers to income before taxes (including capital gains) as a share of
income before transfers. Such figures tell us nothing about whether the
top percentile pays too much or too little in income taxes.
In The Journal of Economic Perspectives (Winter 2007), Messrs.
Piketty and Saez estimated that "the upper 1% of the income distribution
earned 19.6% of total income before tax [in 2004], and paid 41% of the
individual federal income tax." No other major country is so dependent
on so few taxpayers.
A 2008 study of 24 leading economies by the Organization of Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD) concludes that, "Taxation is most
progressively distributed in the United States, probably reflecting the
greater role played there by refundable tax credits, such as the Earned
Income Tax Credit and the Child Tax Credit. . . . Taxes tend to be least
progressive in the Nordic countries (notably, Sweden), France and
Switzerland."
The OECD study—titled "Growing Unequal?"—also found that the ratio
of taxes paid to income received by the top 10% was by far the highest
in the U.S., at 1.35, compared to 1.1 for France, 1.07 for Germany, 1.01
for Japan and 1.0 for Sweden (i.e., the top decile's share of Swedish
taxes is the same as their share of income).
A second fatal flaw is that the large share of income reported by
the upper 1% is largely a consequence of lower tax rates. In a 2010
paper on top incomes co-authored with Anthony Atkinson of Nuffield
College, Messrs. Piketty and Saez note that "higher top marginal tax
rates can reduce top reported earnings." They say "all studies" agree
that higher "top marginal tax rates do seem to negatively affect top
income shares."
What appears to be an increase in top incomes reported on individual
tax returns is often just a predictable taxpayer reaction to lower tax
rates. That should be readily apparent from the nearby table, which uses
data from Messrs. Piketty and Saez to break down the real incomes of the
top 1% by source (excluding interest income and rent).
The first column ("salaries") shows average labor income among the
top 1% reported on W2 forms—from salaries, bonuses and exercised stock
options. A Dec. 13 New York Times article, citing Messrs. Piketty and
Saez, claims, "A big reason for the huge gains at the top is the outsize
pay of executives, bankers and traders." On the contrary, the table
shows that average real pay among the top 1% was no higher at the 2007
peak than it had been in 1999.
In a January 2008 New York Times article, Austan Goolsbee (now
chairman of the President's Council of Economic Advisers) claimed that
"average real salaries (subtracting inflation) for the top 1% of earners
. . . have been growing rapidly regardless of what happened to tax
rates." On the contrary, the top 1% did report higher salaries after the
mid-2003 reduction in top tax rates, but not by enough to offset losses
of the previous three years. By examining the sources of income Mr.
Goolsbee chose to ignore—dividends, capital gains and business income—a
powerful taxpayer response to changing tax rates becomes quite clear.
The second column, for example, shows real capital gains reported
in taxable accounts. President Obama proposes raising the capital gains
tax to 20% on top incomes after the two-year reprieve is over. Yet the
chart shows that the top 1% reported fewer capital gains in the
tech-stock euphoria of 1999-2000 (when the tax rate was 20%) than during
the middling market of 2006-2007. It is doubtful so many gains would
have been reported in 2006-2007 if the tax rate had been 20%. Lower tax
rates on capital gains increase the frequency of asset sales and thus
result in more taxable capital gains on tax returns.
The third column shows a near tripling of average dividend income
from 2002 to 2007. That can only be explained as a behavioral response
to the sharp reduction in top tax rates on dividends, to 15% from 38.6%.
Raising the dividend tax to 20% could easily yield no additional revenue
if it resulted in high-income investors holding fewer dividend- paying
stocks and more corporations using stock buybacks rather than dividends
to reward stockholders.
The last column of the table shows average business income reported
on the top 1% of individual tax returns by subchapter S corporations,
partnerships, proprietorships and many limited liability companies.
After the individual tax rate was brought down to the level of the
corporate tax rate in 2003, business income reported on individual tax
returns became quite large. For the Obama team to argue that higher
taxes on individual incomes would have little impact on business denies
these facts.
If individual tax rates were once again pushed above corporate
rates, some firms, farms and professionals would switch to reporting
income on corporate tax forms to shelter retained earnings. As with
dividends and capital gains, this is another reason that estimated
revenues from higher tax rates are unbelievable.
The Piketty and Saez estimates are irrelevant to questions about
income distribution because they exclude taxes and transfers.
What those
figures do show, however, is that if tax rates on high incomes, capital
gains and dividends were increased in 2013, the top 1%'s reported share
of before-tax income would indeed go way down. That would be partly
because of reduced effort, investment and entrepreneurship. Yet simpler
ways of reducing reported income can leave the after-tax income about
the same (switching from dividend-paying stocks to tax-exempt bonds, or
holding stocks for years).
Once higher tax rates cause the top 1% to report less income, then
top taxpayers would likely pay a much smaller share of taxes, just as
they do in, say, France or Sweden. That would be an ironic consequence
of listening to economists and journalists who form strong opinions
about tax policy on the basis of an essentially irrelevant statistic
about what the top 1%'s share might be if there were not taxes or
transfers.
Mr. Reynolds is a senior fellow at the Cato Institute and the author
of "Income and Wealth" (Greenwood Press 2006).
How can you analyze income distribution without
considering the effect of taxes and transfer payments?